Algeria
Angola
Benin
Botswana
Burkina Faso
Burundi
Cameroon
Cape Verde
Central Afr. Rep.
Chad
Comoros
Congo (Brazzaville)
Congo (Kinshasa)
C�te d'Ivoire
Djibouti
Egypt
Equatorial Guinea
Eritrea
Ethiopia
Gabon
Gambia
Ghana
Guinea
Guinea-Bissau
Kenya
Lesotho
Liberia
Libya
Madagascar
Malawi
Mali
Mauritania
Mauritius
Morocco
Mozambique
Namibia
Niger
Nigeria
Rwanda
São Tomé
Senegal
Seychelles
Sierra Leone
Somalia
South Africa
South Sudan
Sudan
Swaziland
Tanzania
Togo
Tunisia
Uganda
Western Sahara
Zambia
Zimbabwe
|
Get AfricaFocus Bulletin by e-mail!
Format for print or mobile
Africa/Global: Not Pessimism or Optimism but Possibilism
AfricaFocus Bulletin
July 6, 2020 (2020-07-06)
(Reposted from sources cited below)
Editor's Note
�The evidence�gathered both from our own long experience of working
with African governments and from the work of others�is that there
are in fact cadres of thoughtful, public-spirited policy officials
and even politicians; and furthermore that there is ample demand
from wage workers and the intelligentsia for industrial policies
rooted in evidence rather than abstruse economic theory.� -
Christopher Cramer, John Sender, and Arkebe Oqubay
It is relatively easy for any of us to reject the simplified rival
popular stereotypes of �Africa Rising� or the different variants of
Afro-pessimism old or new, by noting the enormous differences among
African countries. But the authors of this new analysis of �African
Economic Development: Evidence, Theory, Policy� go much further in
expanding their version of �possibilism.� They note that there are
profound differences within countries, over time, and by sector.
Almost all generalizations, whether based on old or new theories,
need to be examined critically with evidence in specific cases, and
policy adapted in response to specific experience. There is no
grand formula, and many obstacles to success. But making concrete
steps forward is possible in many cases.
The authors lay out no new �general theory� of their own. But they
clearly argue that successful development must be state-led and
evidence-driven, while both the optimal mix and the possible mixes
of state and private sector actors vary not only by country but by
sector, and by other contingent factors. The book was written prior
to the current Covid-19 pandemic, but their call for adapting
policy to evidence and to unexpected changes remains just as
relevant, if not more relevant, in the period ahead.
[One of the co-authors, Arkebe Oqubay, has several recent commentaries on Covid-19 here.]
The details of the evidence provided in the first nine densely
packed chapters of the book may be difficult to evaluate by those
of us who are not specialists in the subject-matter, including your
editor. But the main points of their arguments are clearly written,
well-documented, and persuasive. The conclusions are summed up in
the final chapter, from which excerpts are presented below, with
permission of the authors and publisher, who are to be commended
for their decision to make the full book available as a pdf
download with a Creative Commons license.
The authors base their findings not only on decades of research
across the continent, but also on sustained dialogue with African
policy makers from around the continent, and, in the case of Arkebe
Oqubay, decades of high-level participation in economic policy
making in Ethiopia.
Their range of expertise is also clear from their many other publications, as google searches will show readily. These include The Oxford Handbook of the Ethiopian Economy, co-edited by two of the authors with Fantu Cheru, and Made in Africa: Industrial Policy in Ethiopia, authored by Arkebe Oqubay. The latter is also available as an open access download.
Another recent book with a similar message about economic development policies, by veteran South African journalist John Matisonn, details the failures of South Africa development policies due both to insistence on conventional economic wisdom and to massive corruption, particularly under the Zuma administration. Matisonn has had unparalleled personal knowledge of South African political actors as a journalist since 1974 and through service as a founding councilor for the Independent Broadcasting Authority from 1994-1998. In his new book Cyril's Choices, he outlines the country's failure to adapt to new technologies and lays out the options for alternative policies for state-led industrial development and the many political obstacles to their adoption. The print edition is only available in South Africa, but an electronic version has recently become available through Amazon.
For previous AfricaFocus Bulletins on African economic issues, visit http://www.africafocus.org/intro-econ.php
+++++++++++++++++++++++++++++++++++++++++++++++++++
Historic Election in Malawi
Opposition leader Lazarus Chakwera won the presidential election on June 23 by a decisive margin, defeating incumbent Peter Mutharika with 58.57% of the vote, the election commission announced. The election was rerun 4 months after Malawi's constitutional court annulled Mr Mutharika's victory in the May 2019 election, citing vote tampering.
For an overview of the election, see the June 27 BBC report.
For insightful analyses, see Kim Yi Dionne and Boniface Dulani in the Washington Post and Golden Matonga in the Mail & Guardian.
++++++++++++++++++++++end editor's note+++++++++++++++++
|
African Economic Development: Evidence, Theory, Policy
by Christopher Cramer, John Sender, and Arkebe Oqubay
Oxford University Press, 2020.
[Excerpts from Chapter 1 and 10. Full text of book is available free on-line from Oxford University Press under a Creative Commons license.]
1.1 The Air that Policy Officials Breathe
...
In this book, we will attempt to introduce some fresh ways of
thinking about the complex economic policy problems facing many
African countries. However, this does not mean we claim to know the
policy answers. Policies have to be designed in detailed ways,
addressing the specific needs of individual countries (and parts of
countries) at particular times. Furthermore, as we argue in this
book, often the most interesting policy design issues emerge during
the process of policy implementation, where they either fail or at
least do not turn out as was intended� policies can then be
adjusted, improvised, and improved in response to these unpredicted
problems.
Policy is made within a global and a structural context. In other
words, countries are shaped by their histories, and their current
options may be constrained by the often hostile characteristics of
the international environment. Even so, we strongly argue that the
keys to generating sustained economic growth and development lie
within African countries, in the form of policy and investment
strategy decisions. In this sense, following the economist Albert
Hirschman, we argue that policy officials can achieve better
results by widening their horizons and adopting an attitude of
�possibilism.�
Sceptics, while perhaps acknowledging that the arguments and
evidence presented in this book may be well founded, will doubtless
assert that there is little chance that any policies arising from
them can or will be implemented in Africa. Some might argue that
there are too many �failed states�; too many economies dominated by
rent-seeking, patrimonialism, and the �politics of the belly�.
Others might argue that the weight of the continent�s colonial past
is too heavy; that the noose of global economic governance rules is
too tight.
Contrary to this, we argue that while the policymaking process is
complex, and its trajectory uncertain, there is often unexpected
scope for adroit policy reasoning. Policies are designed and
implemented through shifting coalitions among political leaders and
policy officials, often blending conflicting interests and logics.
The evidence�gathered both from our own long experience of working
with African governments and from the work of others�is that there
are in fact cadres of thoughtful, public-spirited policy officials
and even politicians; and furthermore that there is ample demand
from wage workers and the intelligentsia for industrial policies
rooted in evidence rather than abstruse economic theory. This
positive assessment is confirmed by discussions with thousands of
policy officials attending more than ten years of residential
schools through the African Programme on Rethinking Development
Economics (APORDE), as well as those taking part in APORDE�s
predecessor at Cambridge and in residential schools in African
countries funded by the Mo Ibrahim Foundation/SOAS Governance for
Development in Africa (GdiA) programme, not to mention by our more
direct experiences of policymaking.
�
1.2 How This Book Differs from Others on the Economics of Africa
The spirit of possibilism is one of the things differentiating this
book from other economics texts on Africa. Many of these are
afflicted either by a profound pessimism�that, due to the legacy
wrought by the continent�s colonial past and the current strictures
of global economic governance imposed by the World Trade
Organization (WTO) and the Bretton Woods Institutions, there is
little that can be done�or by the overly optimistic idea that if
only this or that barrier could be removed then a smooth,
sustained, and inclusive path to economic development would
naturally unfold. Possibilism, by contrast, is a form of realism:
it reflects a �bias for hope� but is rooted in a pragmatic, often
somewhat depressing, awareness of the cruel historical record in
Africa and globally. A record that is, in fact, the history of
capitalist development.
...
We also draw on historical experiences of capitalist development.
This is not, we stress, due to some notion that everything will
ultimately work out the same way it has in, say, the UK or South
Korea; or that the path of African economies is determined by
colonialism or its legacy. The outcomes and trajectories of
capitalist expansion vary hugely and unfold through conflict and
contingency. The implication of this is that past �lessons� should
not be relied upon, and that development trajectories are unlikely
to repeat past experiences. Ethiopia will not follow the same
pattern of development as Taiwan, nor Ghana that of Malaysia.
Nonetheless, we remain convinced that a close study of the
historical record of industrialization and uneven technological
change is important. One reason is that it at least offers some
evidence regarding the complexity of how economic change comes
about, and what the implications of this are for employment and
welfare. The historical evidence, though, should not be used
lightly in order to highlight failure�for example, the alleged
�failure� of the Green Revolution in Africa�or as a cast-iron guide
to appropriate policy in contemporary economies. There is, however,
a hierarchy of plausibility, and evidence from a wide range of
countries trumps anachronistic claims based primarily on
ideological assumptions.
10.4 Priorities for Strategies of Economic Development
One of the main uses of our book is to offer practical suggestions
about how to argue against fashionable policies that are not rooted
in evidence or are theoretically incoherent. We also offer a guide
to implementing some other and less- discussed economic policies,
although we are aware that this guide may only prove useful in
particular political conditions.
The evidence and arguments presented here, especially in Chapters
4�9, lead us to propose the following broad, strategic priorities.
Objective 1: A High Investment Ratio
Governments should promote a high investment ratio as an urgent
priority. Stimulating a sustained high investment to gross domestic
product (GDP) ratio is fundamental to prospects for rapid and
lasting growth and structural change. The historical evidence shows
this clearly. The state has to lead this investment push by making
a commitment to economically productive public spending. This does
not have to be financed by deregulation of the financial sector.
Indeed, liberalizing the financial sector too much and too rapidly,
the evidence shows, undermines such a strategic objective.
Objective 2: National Champion Firms
Rather than supply-side small-is-beautiful entrepreneurship
programmes, policy officials should prioritize the creation and
subsidize the success of large national champions and ensure the
complementarity of public and private initiatives. These large
firms are the ones that can capture the productivity gains from
increasing returns to scale, they are more likely to survive than
small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) (among which there are
typically high rates of collapse), they make a disproportionate
contribution to exports, and they are more likely to create large
numbers of decent and unionized jobs.
Officials should acknowledge the historical evidence that major
private sector investing firms have typically developed thanks to
state support. This support has taken a wide variety of forms,
including: protectionist and �infant industry� policies, the
creation of state-owned enterprises, procurement policies,
supporting legal cartels, laying the base for private sector firms
through public research and development, and other mechanisms of
the �entrepreneurial state�, as well as effective management of
social conflicts and security provision to secure the conditions of
capitalist investment and production.
These are not just policies of historical interest. They are what
governments around the world do (in advanced Organisation for
Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) economies and in
middle and lower-income economies)�with varying degrees of success�
to support successful large firms. It is what the Brazilian state
has done in supporting second-generation bio-tech firms, through
innovative financing mechanisms. Sometimes, major firms emerge from
mutual interests in a tangle of calculation among politicians and
business�winners picking states just as much as states picking
winners. A case in point is Aliko Dangote, founder of the immense
Nigerian and now continent-wide cement firm. Dangote had made
strenuous efforts to develop very close political ties, including
to General Obasanjo, over many years of accumulating rents from a
number of �crony capitalist� trading enterprises. �Dangote used his
close connection to Obasanjo to influence the Nigerian government
to adopt and sustain a Backward Integration Policy (BIP) for the
cement industry in Nigeria� [according to a 2018 study by A.
Akinyoade and C. Uche]. There is clearly an element of the
contingent in these histories, but it certainly helps for officials
to be aware of the scope of the possible, rather than to continue
wasting resources chasing fantasies of development and structural
change through tiny start-ups.
Dangote Cement plant in Obajana, Nigeria. Credit: How We Made It in Africa, 2017.
�It was not too long ago that Nigeria was one of the world�s
largest importers of cement � buying 5.1 million tonnes from
outside its borders in 2011.
But this year [2017] the Nigerian government
announced that it is officially self-sufficient in cement
production � and Dangote Cement is a major reason behind this.� ]
Objective 3: A Rapid Rate of Increase in Imports and in Exports
A publicly led investment boost will necessarily imply a faster
rate of growth of imports. This is only sustainable if there is a
rapid rate of increase in exports. Investment booms tend to lead to
debt problems. This is natural. What matters is preventing a debt
problem becoming a debt crisis. There are all sorts of ways of
negotiating and managing external debt, all of them an important
part of a shrewd strategy, including: ensuring a sensible spread of
debt maturities, limiting non-concessional borrowing, renegotiating
repayment structures, preventing unregulated private sector
borrowing abroad, and others.
Investment�import booms in Africa can also be financed in part by
resort to concessional foreign funds or aid. But just as exposure
to commercial debt is risky, so is too great a reliance on too few
sources of foreign aid, because individual donors may be
unreliable, and because the strings attached to some aid are
difficult to reconcile with the strategic objectives of sustained
economic growth. The real key to managing a rapid rate of growth of
imports is to promote very rapid export expansion. Despite
naysayers, this remains possible. While improving the scope for
(and reducing costs of) intra-African trade may be a boon to
economic activity, it is most unlikely to be an effective
substitute for maximizing exports to demanding (in terms of
quality and phyto-sanitary or labour or other standards) large
higher income markets. Intra-African trade should be a complement
to, not a refuge from, a strategy of wider global economic
integration.
The report available here, from 2019, is an example of one strategy
advocated by the authors as well as an illustration of the kind of
critique and adaptation that they note is essential.
Objective 4: Promoting Investment in Specific Types of Economic
Activity
Investment, especially public investment in infrastructure and
state-owned enter- prises, and government policies designed to
encourage private sector productive investment, needs to be
targeted�directed towards particular types of activity. There are
three particularly important criteria to bear in mind here. First,
invest- ment will have a greater economic and social impact if it
is concentrated in those activities most likely to create growth of
demand for the labour of women with little education. (This should
be combined with measures to keep girls in school longer: both to
improve their own knowledge and skills and to tighten the labour
market.) Such investment may be in high-value agriculture (not just
�agro-processing�), which should be recognized as industrial,
complex, and sophis- ticated production, as well as in urban/peri-
urban manufacturing factories. Complementary policies might support
both types of investment by reducing the financial and social costs
of labour mobility as labour shifts from low to higher-productivity
forms of employment (low-cost accommodation, travel, the cost of
phone network usage for communicating with family and transferring
savings home, or to rural post offices).
Second, investment is needed to underpin rapid export growth. If
possible, the selected activities absorbing unskilled female labour
migrants from rural areas should therefore also make a rapid net
contribution to foreign exchange earnings. That involves a range of
policies including the competitive undervaluation of the exchange
rate.
Third, and complementary to investment in export capacity, we have
shown that it is extremely important to allocate investment
resources to increase the supply of food and other basic wage
goods, which in turn underpins dynamics of investment. Investments
are required to monitor real wages and to intervene rapidly in food
markets to smooth price spikes. In the longer term, investments to
accelerate agricultural production of wage goods and exports
requires R&D expenditures and targeted infrastructure provision
focused on particular crops (e.g. coffee and avocados for exports
and cassava or yams�rather than dairy and poultry�for the poorest
consumers); and it requires betting on the strong, that is, on
farms with a proven track record either in expanding exports or in
producing large marketed surpluses of basic foods for domestic
consumers. Clearly, it would be desirable to combine several
strategic objectives, selecting national and �export� champions
that also employ large numbers of, especially, women from poor
rural backgrounds, or selecting the most dynamic and efficient
producers of wage goods for a low-income domestic mass market that
also employ large numbers of unskilled wage workers (see Chapter
3).
Objective 5: Develop Capability for Monitoring and Disciplining
Designing incentives for well-targeted investment promotion is not
difficult. But it is bordering on pointless to introduce incentives
to firms if there is no parallel development of capacity to monitor
performance and to discipline firms (including by withdrawing
access to exemptions or subsidies, etc.). This quid pro quo�the
reciprocal control mechanism to ensure that firms meet targets for
exports, investment, employment, and productivity�is a sine qua
non of effective policy.
If labour productivity is to improve and if absolute poverty is to
be reduced, there is one aspect of the performance of capitalist
firms that it is particularly important to monitor. In return for
state support, firms need to be set targets not only to increase
exports, but also to encourage the organization and effective voice
of the workers they employ. We are well aware that firms can and do
evade modest levels of employment protection legislation in Africa
(and elsewhere). But minimum wage, health and safety rules, child
protection, gender rights, and other legislation to enforce decent
working conditions may nevertheless be expected to have positive
effects, encouraging the growth of trade unions and strengthening
their negotiating capacity. Even when states appear unable to
impose strict discipline on capitalists�ensuring that all
subsidized enterprises comply with agreed rules�employment
protection legislation can provide a rallying cry and a reference
point for struggles to organize workers. Workers� organizations and
professional associations, together with relatively efficient
compliant firms, may also put pressure on state institutions to
monitor and discipline those firms continuing to compete on the
basis of illegal working conditions and low labour productivity.
There are many good reasons for policymakers to make a serious
effort to create the institutions and mechanisms to monitor
(preferably on a monthly basis) the real wages of all wage workers,
especially the lowest-paid female workers. Publishing trends in
these wages would improve the quality of public debate about
poverty reduction and support Objective 6. It would also help to
rapidly identify failing investment projects and to legitimate
strict disciplinary action by govern- ments against errant
subsidized capitalists. Most importantly, it would provide emerging
workers� organizations with the information necessary to target
their limited resources towards particular sectors and employers.
Objective 6: Protecting Welfare, Profitability, and Political
Stability through Grain Market Management
A key feature of the analysis in this book (chiefly in Chapters 4
and 7) has been to highlight the importance of a non-inflationary
supply of basic wage (especially food) goods. This protects the
ability of firms employing workers to ensure that profitability is
not eroded by wage hikes necessary to allow workers to meet rising
costs of basic living; and it protects politicians from the
political conse- quences of wages not rising sufficiently in such
circumstances. Part of the strategy, (Objective 4) involves
promoting investment in the supply of basic food goods (especially
those cereals purchased by the poorest wage workers). But the
evidence from elsewhere (especially in Asia) is that part of the
strategy also has to involve direct intervention in food grain
markets to prevent price spikes. If export revenues are increasing
and the long-run real international market prices of certain foods
are declining, a successful accumulation strategy in Africa (as
elsewhere) will involve increases in the volume of food imports
(and the manipulation of tariffs on food imports to smooth domestic
price fluctuations).
10.5 Conclusion: Impossible is Nothing
In conclusion, we emphasize two features of the analysis and
argument in this book. First, we have argued that variation
matters. Descriptively, identifying variation in policies and in
performance is crucial to analysis and is often smothered in
averages. Closer attention to variation reveals, for example, that
there is usually more variation within sub-Saharan African
countries�in under- nutrition, in wealth, in access to education,
and so on�than there is between African countries, while,
nonetheless, the variation between countries is itself more
significant than often acknowledged. But we have also argued that
it matters to ask: variation in what?
Much poverty analysis, for example, focuses on categories�simple
geographical distinctions like rural/urban or categories such as
�female-headed households��that can be misleading. These analyses,
we have argued, obscure �intra-category� variation, for example,
inequality within areas classified as rural or huge diversity of
living standards among �smallholders� or �female-headed
households�. And we have suggested some examples of what we argue
are more useful categorical distinctions. The same is the case for
distinctions between broad economic �sectors�, which we have argued
have become even less useful analytically than they may have been
in the past. The blurring of boundaries captured in the idea of
�servicification� and of �the industrialization of freshness� is a
prompt to recalibrate the assessment of which kinds of activity are
most relevant for the objectives of economic policy, which then
leads to the identification of new kinds of variation.
Variation can then become a source of policy possibilism. That it
has been possible to achieve very steep declines in fertility rates
in Rwanda compared to Burundi, despite many similarities of
�structure�, history, and endowments, or in Kenya compared to
Uganda, or Ghana compared to Nigeria (Chapter 2) suggests a clear
role for policy. And the policy history of these countries confirms
a clear commitment to meeting women�s contraceptive needs�sustained
over a lengthy period�in those countries with sharp fertility
declines. Again, the variation in the incidence of insecticide-
treated bed nets or in the equity of their distribution cannot
simply be �read off� from indices of endowments but reflects
purposive policy design and implementation.
Similarly, the fact that some farms have managed to generate far
higher agricultural yields than others within the same agro-
ecological zones suggests a clear role for officials to identify
why and to pursue policies that can clearly secure higher yields on
a much larger area. And differences between African countries in
the rate of adoption of high-yield variety (HYV) seeds reflect
variation in an important policy choice: public spending on
agricultural research (Chapter 9). It is also extremely important
to emphasize, as in Chapter 4, that some African countries have
adopted policies to achieve much higher and more sustained levels
of public sector investment than others.
Second, we have not only shown that mainstream economic analysis
and policy advice is empirically unfounded, has deep theoretical
weaknesses, and has not produced the results insistently claimed,
but we have also provided a coherent (and possibilist) alternative.
But criticizing the mainstream is relatively easy and also
commonplace. Subjecting alternatives to a non-mainstream critique
is more uncommon and, we argue, necessary. Because these
alternatives have so readily and uncritically been accepted by non-
economists in Africa and by heterodox economists, it has been all
too easy for orthodox economists and advisers to deploy dodgy
quantitative evidence to brush these alternative policy proposals
aside.
We have therefore, at the risk of alienating those we have worked
with and often agreed with, also tried to offer an alternative to
the most widespread forms of critique of the mainstream: these
oscillate between stifling impossibilism and fanciful expectations
of capitalism with a human face, of South�South solidarity, of
homogeneous and mutually supportive rural societies, of the triumph
of small-scale capitalism (based on millions of very small farmers
and entrepreneurs).
Above all, we have sought to contribute analysis and evidence that
make it easier for policy officials to pursue some variant of what
Meles Zenawi called the �Sinatra model� of policymaking�assessing
what has been effective in a range of contexts and adapting to
specific African contexts, and then doing it �my way�.
AfricaFocus Bulletin is an independent electronic publication
providing reposted commentary and analysis on African issues, with
a particular focus on U.S. and international policies. AfricaFocus
Bulletin is edited by William Minter.
AfricaFocus Bulletin can be reached at [email protected]. Please
write to this address to suggest material for inclusion. For more
information about reposted material, please contact directly the
original source mentioned.
see http://www.africafocus.org
To subscribe to receive future bulletins by email,
click here.
|